home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the
- preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to
- notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Wash-
- ington, D.C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order that
- corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press.
- SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
- --------
- No. 91-72
- --------
- FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, PETITIONER v.
- TICOR TITLE INSURANCE COMPANY et al.
- on writ of certiorari to the united states court of
- appeals for the third circuit
- [June 12, 1992]
-
- Justice Kennedy delivered the opinion of the Court.
- The Federal Trade Commission filed an administrative
- complaint against six of the nation's largest title insurance
- companies, alleging horizontal price fixing in their fees for
- title searches and title examinations. One company settled
- by consent decree, while five other firms continue to contest
- the matter. The Commission charged the title companies
- with violating 5(a)(1) of the Federal Trade Commission
- Act, 38 Stat. 719, 15 U. S. C. 45(a)(1), which prohibits
- -[u]nfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce.-
- One of the principal defenses the companies assert is state-
- action immunity from antitrust prosecution, as contemplat-
- ed in the line of cases beginning with Parker v. Brown, 317
- U. S. 341 (1943). The Commission rejected this defense, In
- re Ticor Title Ins. Co., 112 F.T.C. 344 (1989), and the firms
- sought review in the United States Court of Appeals for the
- Third Circuit. Ruling that state-action immunity was
- available under the state regulatory schemes in question,
- the Court of Appeals reversed. 922 F. 2d 1122 (1991). We
- granted certiorari. 502 U. S. ___ (1991).
- I
- Title insurance is the business of insuring the record title
- of real property for persons with some interest in the estate,
- including owners, occupiers, and lenders. A title insurance
- policy insures against certain losses or damages sustained
- by reason of a defect in title not shown on the policy or title
- report to which it refers. Before issuing a title insurance
- policy, the insurance company or one of its agents performs
- a title search and examination. The search produces a
- chronological list of the public documents in the chain of
- title to the real property. The examination is a critical
- analysis or interpretation of the condition of title revealed
- by the documents disclosed through this search.
- The title search and examination are major components
- of the insurance company's services. There are certain
- variances from State to State and from policy to policy, but
- a brief summary of the functions performed by the title
- companies can be given. The insurance companies exclude
- from coverage defects uncovered during the search; that is,
- the insurers conduct searches in order to inform the insured
- and to reduce their own liability by identifying and exclud-
- ing known risks. The insured is protected from some losses
- resulting from title defects not discoverable from a search
- of the public records, such as forgery, missing heirs,
- previous marriages, impersonation, or confusion in names.
- They are protected also against errors or mistakes in the
- search and examination. Negligence need not be proved in
- order to recover. Title insurance also includes the obliga-
- tion to defend in the event that an insured is sued by
- reason of some defect within the scope of the policy's
- guarantee.
- The title insurance industry earned $1.35 billion gross
- revenues in 1982, and respondents accounted for 57 percent
- of that amount. Four of respondents are the nation's
- largest title insurance companies: Ticor Title Insurance
- Co., with 16.5 percent of the market; Chicago Title Insur-
- ance Co., with 12.8 percent; Lawyers Title Insurance Co.,
- with 12 percent; and SAFECO Title Insurance Co. (now
- operating under the name Security Union Title Insurance
- Co.), with 10.3 percent. Stewart Title Guarantee Co., with
- 5.4 percent of the market, is the country's eighth largest
- title insurer, with a strong position in the West and
- Southwest.
- The Commission issued an administrative complaint in
- 1985. Horizontal price-fixing was alleged in these terms:
- -`Respondents have agreed on the price to be charged
- for title search and examination services or settlement
- services through rating bureaus in various states.
- Examples of states in which one or more of the Respon-
- dents have fixed prices with other Respondents or other
- competitors for all or part of their search and examina-
- tion services or settlement services are Arizona,
- Connecticut, Idaho, Louisiana, Montana, New Jersey,
- New Mexico, New York, Ohio, Oregon, Pennsylvania,
- Wisconsin and Wyoming.'- 112 F.T.C., at 346.
- The Commission did not challenge the insurers' practice of
- setting uniform rates for insurance against the risk of loss
- from defective titles, but only the practice of setting uniform
- rates for the title search, examination, and settlement,
- aspects of the business which, the Commission alleges, do
- not involve insurance.
- Before the Administrative Law Judge (ALJ), the respon-
- dents defended against liability on three related grounds.
- First, they maintained that the challenged conduct is
- exempt from antitrust scrutiny under the McCarran-
- Ferguson Act, 59 Stat. 34, 15 U. S. C. 1012(b), which
- confers antitrust immunity over the -business of insurance-
- to the extent regulated by state law. Second, they argued
- that their collective ratemaking activities are exempt under
- the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, which places certain -[j]oint
- efforts to influence public officials- beyond the reach of the
- antitrust laws. Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U. S. 657,
- 670 (1965); Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v. Noerr
- Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U. S. 127, 136 (1961). Third,
- respondents contended their activities are entitled to state-
- action immunity, which permits anticompetitive conduct if
- authorized and supervised by state officials. See California
- Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v. Midcal Aluminum Inc., 445
- U. S. 97 (1980); Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341 (1943). As
- to one State, Ohio, the respondents contended that the
- rates for title search, examination, and settlement had not
- been set by a rating bureau.
- Title insurance company rates and practices in thirteen
- States were the subject of the initial complaint. Before the
- matter was decided by the ALJ, the Commission declined to
- pursue its complaint with regard to fees in five of these
- States, Louisiana, New Mexico, New York, Oregon, and
- Wyoming. Upon the recommendation of the ALJ, the
- Commission did not pursue its complaint with regard to
- fees in two additional States, Idaho and Ohio. This left six
- States in which the Commission found antitrust violations,
- but in two of these States, New Jersey and Pennsylvania,
- the Commission conceded the issue on which certiorari was
- sought here, so the regulatory regimes in these two States
- are not before us. Four States remain in which violations
- were alleged: Connecticut, Wisconsin, Arizona, and
- Montana.
- The ALJ held that the rates for search and examination
- services had been fixed in these four States. For reasons
- we need not pause to examine, the ALJ rejected the
- McCarran-Ferguson and Noerr-Pennington defenses. The
- ALJ then turned his attention to the question of state-
- action immunity. A summary of the ALJ's extensive
- findings on this point is necessary for a full understanding
- of the decisions reached at each level of the proceedings in
- the case.
- Rating bureaus are private entities organized by title
- insurance companies to establish uniform rates for their
- members. The ALJ found no evidence that the collective
- setting of title insurance rates through rating bureaus is a
- way of pooling risk information. Indeed, he found no
- evidence that any title insurer sets rates according to
- actuarial loss experience. Instead, the ALJ found that the
- usual practice is for rating bureaus to set rates according to
- profitability studies that focus on the costs of conducting
- searches and examinations. Uniform rates are set notwith-
- standing differences in efficiencies and costs among individ-
- ual members.
- The ALJ described the regulatory regimes for title
- insurance rates in the four States still at issue. In each
- one, the title insurance rating bureau was licensed by the
- State and authorized to establish joint rates for its mem-
- bers. Each of the four States used what has come to be
- called a -negative option- system to approve rate filings by
- the bureaus. Under a negative option system, the rating
- bureau filed rates for title searches and title examinations
- with the state insurance office. The rates became effective
- unless the State rejected them within a specified period,
- such as 30 days. Although the negative option system
- provided a theoretical mechanism for substantive review,
- the ALJ determined, after making detailed findings
- regarding the operation of each regulatory regime, that the
- rate filings were subject to minimal scrutiny by state
- regulators.
- In Connecticut the State Insurance Department has the
- authority to audit the rating bureau and hold hearings
- regarding rates, but it has not done so. The Connecticut
- rating bureau filed only two major rate increases, in 1966
- and in 1981. The circumstances behind the 1966 rate
- increase are somewhat obscure. The ALJ found that the
- Insurance Department asked the rating bureau to submit
- additional information justifying the increase, and later
- approved the rate increase although there is no evidence
- the additional information was provided. In 1981 the
- Connecticut rating bureau filed for a 20 percent rate
- increase. The factual background for this rate increase is
- better developed though the testimony was somewhat
- inconsistent. A state insurance official testified that he
- reviewed the rate increase with care and discussed various
- components of the increase with the rating bureau. The
- same official testified, however, that he lacked the authority
- to question certain expense data he considered quite high.
- In Wisconsin the State Insurance Commissioner is
- required to examine the rating bureau at regular intervals
- and authorized to reject rates through a process of hearings.
- Neither has been done. The Wisconsin rating bureau made
- major rate filings in 1971, 1981, and 1982. The 1971 rate
- filing was approved in 1971 although supporting justifica-
- tion, which had been requested by the State Insurance
- Commissioner, was not provided until 1978. The 1981 rate
- filing requested an 11 percent rate increase. The increase
- was approved after the office of the Insurance Commission-
- er checked the supporting data for accuracy. No one in the
- agency inquired into insurer expenses, though an official
- testified that substantive scrutiny would not be possible
- without that inquiry. The 1982 rate increase received but
- a cursory reading at the office of the Insurance Commis-
- sioner. The supporting materials were not checked for
- accuracy, though in the absence of an objection by the
- agency, the rate increase went into effect.
- In Arizona the Insurance Director was required to
- examine the rating bureau at least once every five years.
- It was not done. In 1980 the State Insurance Department
- announced a comprehensive investigation of the rating
- bureau. It was not conducted. The rating bureau spent
- most of its time justifying its escrow rates. Following
- settlement in 1981 of a federal civil suit challenging the
- joint fixing of escrow rates, the rating bureau went out of
- business without having made any major rate filings,
- though it had proposed minor rate adjustments.
- In Montana the rating bureau made its only major rate
- filing in 1983. In connection with it, a representative of the
- rating bureau met with officials of the State Insurance
- Department. He was told that the filed rates could go into
- immediate effect though further profit data would have to
- be provided. The ALJ found no evidence that the additional
- data were furnished.
- To complete the background, the ALJ observed that none
- of the rating bureaus are now active. The respondents
- abandoned them between 1981 and 1985 in response to
- numerous private treble damage suits, so by the time the
- Commission filed its formal complaint in 1985, the rating
- bureaus had been dismantled. The ALJ held that the case
- is not moot, though, because nothing would preclude
- respondents from resuming the conduct challenged by the
- Commission. See United States v. W. T. Grant Co., 345
- U. S. 629, 632-633 (1953).
- These factual determinations established, the ALJ
- addressed the two-part test that must be satisfied for state-
- action immunity under the antitrust laws, the test we set
- out in California Retail Liquor Dealers Assn. v. Midcal
- Aluminum, Inc., 445 U. S. 97 (1980). A state law or
- regulatory scheme cannot be the basis for antitrust immuni-
- ty unless, first, the State has articulated a clear and
- affirmative policy to allow the anticompetitive conduct, and
- second, the State provides active supervision of anticompeti-
- tive conduct undertaken by private actors. Id., at 105. The
- Commission having conceded that the first part of the test
- was satisfied in the four States still at issue, the immunity
- question, beginning with the hearings before the ALJ and
- in all later proceedings, has turned upon the proper
- interpretation and application of Midcal's active supervision
- requirement. The ALJ found the active supervision test
- was met in Arizona and Montana but not in Connecticut or
- Wisconsin.
- On review of the ALJ's decision, the Commission held
- that none of the four states had conducted sufficient
- supervision, so that the title companies were not entitled to
- immunity in any of those jurisdictions. The Court of
- Appeals for the Third Circuit disagreed with the Commis-
- sion, adopting the approach of the First Circuit in New
- England Motor Rate Bureau, Inc., v. FTC, 908 F. 2d 1064
- (1990), which had held that the existence of a state regula-
- tory program, if staffed, funded, and empowered by law,
- satisfied the requirement of active supervision. Id., at
- 1071. Under this standard, the Court of Appeals for the
- Third Circuit ruled that the active state supervision
- requirement was met in all four states and held that the
- respondents' conduct was entitled to state action immunity
- in each of them.
- We granted certiorari to consider two questions: First,
- whether the Third Circuit was correct in its statement of
- the law and in its application of law to fact, and second,
- whether the Third Circuit exceeded its authority by
- departing from the factual findings entered by the ALJ and
- adopted by the Commission. Before this Court, the parties
- have confined their briefing on the first of these questions
- to the regulatory regimes of Wisconsin and Montana, and
- focused on the regulatory regimes of Connecticut and
- Arizona in briefing on the second question. We now reverse
- the Court of Appeals under the first question and remand
- for further proceedings under the second.
- II
- The preservation of the free market and of a system of
- free enterprise without price fixing or cartels is essential to
- economic freedom. United States v. Topco Associates, Inc.,
- 405 U. S. 596, 610 (1972). A national policy of such a
- pervasive and fundamental character is an essential part of
- the economic and legal system within which the separate
- States administer their own laws for the protection and
- advancement of their people. Continued enforcement of the
- national antitrust policy grants the States more freedom,
- not less, in deciding whether to subject discrete parts of the
- economy to additional regulations and controls. Against
- this background, in Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341 (1943),
- we upheld a state-supervised market sharing scheme
- against a Sherman Act challenge. We announced the
- doctrine that federal antitrust laws are subject to superses-
- sion by state regulatory programs. Our decision was
- grounded in principles of federalism. Id., at 350-352.
- The principle of freedom of action for the States, adopted
- to foster and preserve the federal system, explains the later
- evolution and application of the Parker doctrine in our
- decisions in Midcal, supra, and Patrick v. Burget, 486 U. S.
- 94 (1988). In Midcal we invalidated a California statute
- forbidding licensees in the wine trade from selling below
- prices set by the producer. There we announced the two-
- part test applicable to instances where private parties
- participate in a price fixing regime. -First, the challenged
- restraint must be one clearly articulated and affirmatively
- expressed as state policy; second, the policy must be
- actively supervised by the State itself.- Midcal, 445 U. S.,
- at 105 (internal quotation marks omitted). Midcal confirms
- that while a State may not confer antitrust immunity on
- private persons by fiat, it may displace competition with
- active state supervision if the displacement is both intended
- by the State and implemented in its specific details. Actual
- state involvement, not deference to private price fixing
- arrangements under the general auspices of state law, is
- the precondition for immunity from federal law. Immunity
- is conferred out of respect for ongoing regulation by the
- State, not out of respect for the economics of price restraint.
- In Midcal we found that the intent to restrain prices was
- expressed with sufficient precision so that the first part of
- the test was met, but that the absence of state participation
- in the mechanics of the price posting was so apparent that
- the requirement of active supervision had not been met.
- Ibid.
- The rationale was further elaborated in Patrick v. Burget.
- In Patrick it had been alleged that private physicians
- participated in the State's peer review system in order to
- injure or destroy competition by denying hospital privileges
- to a physician who had begun a competing clinic. We
- referred to the purpose of preserving the State's own
- administrative policies, as distinct from allowing private
- parties to foreclose competition, in the following passage:
- -The active supervision requirement stems from the
- recognition that where a private party is engaging in
- the anticompetitive activity, there is a real danger that
- he is acting to further his own interests, rather than
- the governmental interests of the State. . . . The re-
- quirement is designed to ensure that the state-action
- doctrine will shelter only the particular anticompetitive
- acts of private parties that, in the judgment of the
- State, actually further state regulatory policies. To
- accomplish this purpose, the active supervision require-
- ment mandates that the State exercise ultimate control
- over the challenged anticompetitive conduct. . . . The
- mere presence of some state involvement or monitoring
- does not suffice. . . . The active supervision prong of the
- Midcal test requires that state officials have and
- exercise power to review particular anticompetitive acts
- of private parties and disapprove those that fail to
- accord with state policy. Absent such a program of
- supervision, there is no realistic assurance that a
- private party's anticompetitive conduct promotes state
- policy, rather than merely the party's individual
- interests.- 486 U. S., at 100-101 (internal quotation
- marks and citations omitted).
- Because the particular anticompetitive conduct at issue in
- Patrick had not been supervised by governmental actors, we
- decided that the actions of the peer review committee were
- not entitled to state-action immunity. Id., at 106.
- Our decisions make clear that the purpose of the active
- supervision inquiry is not to determine whether the State
- has met some normative standard, such as efficiency, in its
- regulatory practices. Its purpose is to determine whether
- the State has exercised sufficient independent judgment
- and control so that the details of the rates or prices have
- been established as a product of deliberate state interven-
- tion, not simply by agreement among private parties. Much
- as in causation inquiries, the analysis asks whether the
- State has played a substantial role in determining the
- specifics of the economic policy. The question is not how
- well state regulation works but whether the anticompetitive
- scheme is the State's own.
- Although the point bears but brief mention, we observe
- that our prior cases considered state-action immunity
- against actions brought under the Sherman Act, and this
- case arises under the Federal Trade Commission, Act. The
- Commission has argued at other times that state-action
- immunity does not apply to Commission action under 5
- of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U. S. C. 45. See
- U. S. Bureau of Consumer Protection, Staff Report to the
- Federal Trade Commission on Prescription Drug Price
- Disclosures, Chs. VI (B) and (C) (1975); see also Note, The
- State Action Exemption and Antitrust Enforcement under
- the Federal Trade Commission Act, 89 Harv. L. Rev. 715
- (1976). A leading treatise has expressed its skepticism of
- this view. See 1 P. Areeda & D. Turner, Antitrust Law
- -218 (1978). We need not determine whether the antitrust
- statutes can be distinguished on this basis, because the
- Commission does not assert any superior pre-emption
- authority in the instant matter. We apply our prior cases
- to the one before us.
- The respondents contend that principles of federalism
- justify a broad interpretation of state-action immunity, but
- there is a powerful refutation of their viewpoint in the
- briefs that were filed in this case. The State of Wisconsin,
- joined by Montana and 34 other States, has filed a brief as
- amici curiae on the precise point. These States deny that
- respondents' broad immunity rule would serve the States'
- best interests. We are in agreement with the amici
- submission.
- If the States must act in the shadow of state-action
- immunity whenever they enter the realm of economic
- regulation, then our doctrine will impede their freedom of
- action, not advance it. The fact of the matter is that the
- States regulate their economies in many ways not inconsis-
- tent with the antitrust laws. For example, Oregon may
- provide for peer review by its physicians without approving
- anticompetitive conduct by them. See Patrick, supra, at
- 105. Or Michigan may regulate its public utilities without
- authorizing monopolization in the market for electric light
- bulbs. See Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U. S. 579, 596
- (1976). So we have held that state-action immunity is
- disfavored, much as are repeals by implication. Lafayette
- v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U. S. 389, 398-399
- (1978). By adhering in most cases to fundamental and
- accepted assumptions about the benefits of competition
- within the framework of the antitrust laws, we increase the
- States' regulatory flexibility.
- States must accept political responsibility for actions they
- intend to undertake. It is quite a different matter, howev-
- er, for federal law to compel a result that the States do not
- intend but for which they are held to account. Federalism
- serves to assign political responsibility, not to obscure it.
- Neither federalism nor political responsibility is well served
- by a rule that essential national policies are displaced by
- state regulations intended to achieve more limited ends.
- For States which do choose to displace the free market with
- regulation, our insistence on real compliance with both
- parts of the Midcal test will serve to make clear that the
- State is responsible for the price fixing it has sanctioned
- and undertaken to control.
- The respondents contend that these concerns are better
- addressed by the requirement that the States articulate a
- clear policy to displace the antitrust laws with their own
- forms of economic regulation. This contention misappre-
- hends the close relation between Midcal's two elements.
- Both are directed at ensuring that particular anticompe-
- titive mechanisms operate because of a deliberate and
- intended state policy. See Patrick, supra, at 100. In the
- usual case, Midcal's requirement that the State articulate
- a clear policy shows little more than that the State has not
- acted through inadvertence; it cannot alone ensure, as
- required by our precedents, that particular anticompetitive
- conduct has been approved by the State. It seems plain,
- moreover, in light of the amici curiae brief to which we
- have referred, that sole reliance on the requirement of clear
- articulation will not allow the regulatory flexibility that
- these States deem necessary. For States whose object it is
- to benefit their citizens through regulation, a broad doctrine
- of state-action immunity may serve as nothing more than
- an attractive nuisance in the economic sphere. To oppose
- these pressures, sole reliance on the requirement of clear
- articulation could become a rather meaningless formal
- constraint.
- III
- In the case before us, the Court of Appeals relied upon a
- formulation of the active supervision requirement articulat-
- ed by the First Circuit:
- -`Where . . . the state's program is in place, is staffed
- and funded, grants to the state officials ample power
- and the duty to regulate pursuant to declared stan-
- dards of state policy, is enforceable in the state's courts,
- and demonstrates some basic level of activity directed
- towards seeing that the private actors carry out the
- state's policy and not simply their own policy, more
- need not be established.'- 922 F. 2d, at 1136, quoting
- New England Motor Rate Bureau, Inc. v. FTC, 908 F.
- 2d 1064, 1071 (CA1 1990).
- Based on this standard, the Third Circuit ruled that the
- active supervision requirement was met in all four states,
- and held that the respondents' conduct was entitled to
- state-action immunity from antitrust liability. 992 F. 2d, at
- 1140.
- While in theory the standard articulated by the First
- Circuit might be applied in a manner consistent with our
- precedents, it seems to us insufficient to establish the
- requisite level of active supervision. The criteria set forth
- by the First Circuit may have some relevance as the
- beginning point of the active state supervision inquiry, but
- the analysis cannot end there. Where prices or rates are
- set as an initial matter by private parties, subject only to a
- veto if the State chooses to exercise it, the party claiming
- the immunity must show that state officials have undertak-
- en the necessary steps to determine the specifics of the
- price-fixing or ratesetting scheme. The mere potential for
- state supervision is not an adequate substitute for a
- decision by the State. Under these standards, we must
- conclude that there was no active supervision in either
- Wisconsin or Montana.
- The respondents point out that in Wisconsin and Mon-
- tana the rating bureaus filed rates with state agencies and
- that in both States the so-called negative option rule
- prevailed. The rates became effective unless they were
- rejected within a set time. It is said that as a matter of law
- in those States inaction signified substantive approval.
- This proposition cannot be reconciled, however, with the
- detailed findings, entered by the ALJ and adopted by the
- Commission, which demonstrate that the potential for state
- supervision was not realized in fact. The ALJ found, and
- the Commission agreed, that at most the rate filings were
- checked for mathematical accuracy. Some were unchecked
- altogether. In Montana, a rate filing became effective
- despite the failure of the rating bureau to provide addition-
- al requested information. In Wisconsin, additional informa-
- tion was provided after a lapse of seven years, during which
- time the rate filing remained in effect. These findings are
- fatal to respondents' attempts to portray the state regulato-
- ry regimes as providing the necessary component of active
- supervision. The findings demonstrate that, whatever the
- potential for state regulatory review in Wisconsin and
- Montana, active state supervision did not occur. In the
- absence of active supervision in fact, there can be no state-
- action immunity for what were otherwise private price
- fixing arrangements. And as in Patrick, the availability of
- state judicial review could not fill the void. Because of the
- state agencies' limited role and participation, state judicial
- review was likewise limited. See Patrick, 486 U. S., at
- 103-105.
- Our decision in Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference,
- Inc. v. United States, 471 U. S. 48 (1985), though it too
- involved a negative option regime, is not to the contrary.
- The question there was whether the first part of the Midcal
- test was met, the Government's contention being that a
- pricing policy is not an articulated one unless the practice
- is compelled. We rejected that assertion and undertook no
- real examination of the active supervision aspect of the
- case, for the Government conceded that the second part of
- the test had been met. Id., at 62, 66. The concession was
- against the background of a district court determination
- that, although submitted rates could go into effect without
- further state activity, the State had ordered and held rate-
- making hearings on a consistent basis, using the industry
- submissions as the beginning point. See United States v.
- Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference, Inc., 467 F. Supp.
- 471, 476-477 (ND Ga. 1979). In the case before us, of
- course, the Government concedes the first part of the
- Midcal requirement and litigates the second; and there is
- no finding of substantial state participation in the rate
- setting scheme.
- This case involves horizontal price fixing under a vague
- imprimatur in form and agency inaction in fact. No
- antitrust offense is more pernicious than price fixing. FTC
- v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Assn., 493 U. S. 411, 434,
- n.16 (1990). In this context, we decline to formulate a rule
- that would lead to a finding of active state supervision
- where in fact there was none. Our decision should be read
- in light of the gravity of the antitrust offense, the involve-
- ment of private actors throughout, and the clear absence of
- state supervision. We do not imply that some particular
- form of state or local regulation is required to achieve ends
- other than the establishment of uniform prices. Cf.
- Columbia v. Omni Outdoor Advertising, Inc., 499 U. S. ___
- (1991) (city billboard zoning ordinance entitled to state-
- action immunity). We do not have before us a case in
- which governmental actors made unilateral decisions
- without participation by private actors. Cf. Fisher v.
- Berkeley, 475 U. S. 260 (1986) (private actors not liable
- without private action). And we do not here call into
- question a regulatory regime in which sampling techniques
- or a specified rate of return allow state regulators to
- provide comprehensive supervision without complete
- control, or in which there was an infrequent lapse of state
- supervision. Cf. 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 479 U. S. 335,
- 344, n.6 (1987) (a statute specifying the margin between
- wholesale and retail prices may satisfy the active supervi-
- sion requirement). In the circumstances of this case,
- however, we conclude that the acts of the respondents in
- the States of Montana and Wisconsin are not immune from
- antitrust liability.
- IV
- In granting certiorari we undertook to review the further
- contention by the Commission that the Court of Appeals
- was incorrect in disregarding the Commission's findings as
- to the extent of state supervision. The parties have focused
- their briefing on this question on the regulatory schemes of
- Connecticut and Arizona. We think the Court of Appeals
- should have the opportunity to reexamine its determina-
- tions with respect to these latter two States in light of the
- views we have expressed.
- The judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed and the
- case is remanded for further proceedings consistent with
- this opinion.
- It is so ordered.
-